Market Definition and Market Power

AuthorJohn S. Tyhurst
Pages140-182
140
C H A P T E R 4
MAR KET DEFINITION
AND MARKET POWER
A. INTRODUCT ION
Market def‌inition is usually a t hreshold, and sometimes a decisive,
issue in competition law cases. In the Canada (Director of Investigation
and Research) v Southam Inc merger case, for example, the central issue
before the Supreme Court of Canada was whether the acquired com-
munity newspapers were in the same “relevant market” as two daily
newspapers, the Vancouver Sun and Vancouver Province.1 Southam
owned the two daily news papers. In 1989, it acquired thirteen commun-
ity newspapers and cert ain other publishing concerns. In 1990, an appli-
cation was f‌iled under section 92 of the Competition Act by the Di rector
(now Commissioner of Competition) seeking to have Southam divest
the largest community paper s in the Greater Vancouver area, the North
Shore News and Vancouver Courier, as well as the Real Estate Weekly,
on the basis that t hose acquisitions were “likely to prevent or lessen
competition substantially” i n the retail print advertising and rea l estate
print advertising m arkets in the Lower Mainland area of Vancouver.
The Competit ion Tribunal found t hat the commun ity newspaper s
were not in the same market as the da ilies, on the basis that they ser ved
dierent print advertising markets. It held that the dailies appealed
to large national advertisers (like banks and automobile companies)
1 Canada (Director of Investigation a nd Research) v Southam Inc, [1997] 1 SCR 748
[Southam SCC], overturnin g [1995] 3 FC 557 (CA) [Southam FCA].
Market Def‌init ion and Market Power 141
seeking coverage throughout a metropolitan area, while t he community
papers appealed to local advert isers (such as smaller retailers), whose
customers live within a cer tain district.2 The acqu isition by Southam
of the two community newspapers was permitted because they were
found not to compete in the same market. That f‌inding was ultimately
upheld by the Supreme Court. The Supreme Court overturned the Fed-
eral Court of Appeal, f‌inding that the Tribunal’s determination on the
relevant market was reasonable and should have been shown deference
by the appeal court.3
A price f‌ixing ca se which turned on market def‌inition was R v Clarke
Transport Inc. An agreement to f‌ix prices and allocate customers wa s
proven. The trial judge, Moldaver J (as he then was), found that “I am
satisf‌ied beyond any reasonable doubt that the f‌ive corporate accused
conspired amongst themselves and with others in respect of prices for
the delivery of freight by rail f rom Toronto to various destinations in
Western Canada.”4 However, prior to amendments to the Act in 2009,
the Crown had to prove that the conspiracy resulted in an “undue less-
ening of competition.” This required that the co-conspir ators possess
some market power in a relevant market. Justice Moldaver was not satis-
f‌ied that the relevant market was re stricted to freight transportation by
railway “pool” car, as the Crown alleged. He concluded that “pool car
operators, truckers and inter modal operators were equally capable of
moving and indeed did move the identical k inds of freight on behalf
of shipper/customers from Ontario to points west.”5 He was unable to
conclude that the pool car conspirators had m arket power in the broader
market for freight transport ation. They were acquitted.
An example of market def‌inition playing a decisive role in a mon-
opolization case under the American Sherman Act was the 1947 Du
Pont case.6 Du Pont produced almost 75 percent of the cellophane sold
in the United States at that time, but cellophane constituted less than
20percent of the sales of all “f‌lexible packaging material” (including
wax paper, aluminum foil, etc.). While the US Supreme Court found that
DuPont had a monopoly in cellophane by virt ue of its patent protection
and licensing agreements, it noted that “[t]he court below held that
the ‘great sensitivity of customers in the f‌lexible packaging markets to
2 Canada (Director of Investigatio n and Research) v Southam Inc (1992), 43 CPR (3d)
161 (CCT) [Southam CCT].
3 Southam SCC, above note 1.
4 R v Clarke Transport Canada Inc (1995), 130 DLR (4th) 500 (Ont Gen Div) at
para 45.
5 Ibid at para 133.
6 United States v EI du Pont de Nemours and Co, 351 US 377 (1947).
CANA DIAN COMPETI TION LAW AND POLICY142
price or quality changes’ prevented du Pont from posses sing monopoly
control over price.”7 It held (consistent with the lower court’s determin-
ation): “du Pont should not be found to monopolize cellophane when
that product has the competition and intercha ngeability with other
wrappings that th is record shows.8 While the result has been crit icized
because the Court fai led to take into account that Du Pont’s prices were
already elevated by, and more price sensitive due to, its existing cello-
phane monopoly (the so-called cellophane fallacy di scussed below), the
case illustr ates again how market def‌inition can b e a decisive threshold
issue i n competition law.
B. M ARK ET DEFINITION AS A STEP IN
ASSESSI NG MA RK ET POW ER
1) The Meaning and Relevance of “Market Power”
Market def‌inition was required in the three cases discussed above
because the applicable legal test s involved a determination of the impact
of the conduct in question on competition. Market def‌inition provides a
framework within which to assess competitive eects. The Competition
Act requires that the Competition Tribunal asse ss whether or not the
party’s or parties’ conduct has had, or would have, the following eect:
“substa ntial prevention or lessening of competition” (for mergers, ver-
tical practices, abuse of domin ance, anti-competitive agreements)9 and
“adverse eect on competition in a market” (for refusal to supply,
resale price mainten ance).10
These tests have been held to require some degree of impact on
market power. “Market power” was def‌ined by the Supreme Court in
Ter vi ta a s follows:
Market power is the abilit y to “prof‌itably inf‌luence price, qual-
ity, variety, service, adverti sing, innovation or other dimensions of
competition.” . . . Or, in other words, market power i s “the ability to
maintai n prices above the competitive level for a considerable period
of time without such action be ing unprof‌itable” . . . where “price” is
7 Ibid at 400.
8 Ibid at 404.
9 Competition Act, RSC 1985, c C-34, ss 77, 79, and 82.
10 Ibid, ss 75 & 76.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT