Compensation for Harm to Economic Interests

AuthorJamie Cassels
ProfessionProfessor of Law University of Victoria
Pages15-62
CHAPTER
2
COMPENSATION
FOR
HARM
TO
ECONOMIC
INTERESTS
A.
INTRODUCTION
This chapter canvasses
the
principles
of
recovery
for
harm
to
economic
interests.
It
focuses
primarily upon contract law, since contract
is the
primary means
by
which persons establish economic
rights.
However,
tort
law
also
offers
protection against economic loss.
For
example,
the
action
for
deceit
or
fraud
is of
ancient origin. More recently,
the
protec-
tion
of
economic interests
in
tort
has
been
further
extended through
the
development
of the
tort
of
negligent misrepresentation
and a
cau-
tious expansion
of
recovery
of
economic
losses
caused
by
negligence.
At
one
level
of
generality, there
is no
real
difference
in the way in
which damages
are
calculated
in
contract
and
tort.
Both
are
based
on
the
principle
of
restitutio
in
integrum
that
the
plaintiff
is to be
made
whole. This
is
accomplished
by
awarding
a sum of
money that will
put
the
plaintiff
in the
position
as
though
the
wrong
had not
been done.
However,
in
application, this principle works
differently
in
contract
and
tort.
Since contracts create expectations about
the
future,
the
stan-
dard measure
of
recovery
is
expectation damages. Tort
law
protects
interests
in the
present
and the
primary measure
of
damages
is the
reli-
ance
or
restoration measure.
This
chapter considers
the
principles
regarding both measures
of
damages.
15
16
REMEDIES:
THE LAW OF
DAMAGES
B.
BREACH
OF
CONTRACT:
THE
EXPECTATION
MEASURE
1)
Introduction
The
ordinary measure
of
damages
in
actions
for
breach
of
contract
is
the
expectation measure. Expectation damages
are
forward-looking.
They
do not
merely compensate persons
for
positive losses
suffered
as
the
result
of a
wrong,
but
give
to the
plaintiff
the
benefits expected
as a
result
of a
promise. Expectation damages
aim to put the
plaintiff
in the
position
she
would have been
in had the
contract been performed.
In
the
case
of
Wertheim
v.
Chicoutimi
Pulp
Co.,1
for
example,
the
Court
stated:
"[I]t
is the
general intention
of the law
that,
in
giving damages
for
breach
of
contract,
the
party complaining should,
so far as it can be
done
by
money,
be
placed
in the
same position
as he
would have been
in if the
contract
had
been performed."
Expectation
damages
are
designed
to
secure
for the
plaintiff
the
benefit
of the
contract. Most generally, they
can be
calculated
by
deter-
mining
the
difference
between
the
position
that
the
plaintiff
would
have
occupied,
had the
contract
been
performed,
and the
position
that
the
plain-
tiff
is
actually
in as a
result
of
breach
or
non-performance
of
the
contract.
Sometimes,
when there
are no
consequential
or
out-of-pocket
losses
to the
plaintiff
associated with
the
contract,
the
expectation mea-
sure
of
damages will
be
calculated simply
by
reference
to the net
gain
that
the
plaintiff
would have obtained
as a
result
of the
contract.
For
example,
if the
contract
is for the
sale
of
goods
at
$100,
and at the
time
the
defendant
fails
to
deliver
the
goods, they
are
worth $120,
the
expectation damages
are $20 the net
benefit that would have been
obtained
by the
plaintiff
(assuming that
the
plaintiff
has not
prepaid).
Giving
this
amount
in
damages
will
put the
plaintiff (financially)
in the
same
position
as
though
he had
received
the
goods.
On
other occa-
sions,
a
plaintiff
will have incurred additional consequential
losses
that
must also
be
compensated
if he is to be put in the
position
he
would
have been
in had the
contract been performed.
For
example,
in the
sit-
uation above,
if the
plaintiff
had
arranged
and
paid
for
transportation
for
the
expected goods,
the
damages award would also have
to
include
the
wasted expenditure. Alternatively,
the
plaintiff
may
have been
intending
to use the
goods
for
some profit-making enterprise
and as a
result
of the
breach will have lost
an
opportunity
to
make
a
profit.
The
1
[1911]
A.C.
301 at
307;
see
also
Robinson
v.
Harman
(1848),
1
Ex.D.
850 at
855,
Parke
B.
Compensation
for
Harm
to
Economic Interests
17
extent
to
which these additional consequential losses
are
recoverable
is
discussed
in
greater detail below.
2) Why Are
Expectation Damages
the
Standard Measure
in
Contract
Law?
Much
legal scholarship
has
been devoted
to the
question
of why
con-
tract
law
should protect
the
expectation interest.
It has
been observed
that
the
moral
force
of the
restitution
and
reliance interests
is
much
stronger
and
more widely accepted than
the
expectation
interest.2
The
restitution interest
reflects
the
widely held sentiment that obtaining
a
benefit
by
fraud,
deceit,
or
promise-breaking
is
wrong
and
that
unjustly
acquired gains should
be
disgorged.
The
reliance interest sim-
ilarly
rests upon
a
widely shared moral sentiment that injuries
suffered
by
reason
of a
broken promise
or
misrepresentation
should
be
made
whole; that
if a
person relies upon another
and the
other
fails
to
keep
his
word,
any
losses
suffered
should
be
compensated.
But the
expecta-
tion interest goes much
further
and
grants
to the
plaintiff
compensa-
tion
not
only
for the
loss
suffered
but for the
gain anticipated.
The
plaintiffs
"loss"
is
defined
in
terms
of
something
he or she
never had.
Thus,
it
remains
a
matter
of
considerable interest among legal scholars
why
contract
law
pursues
the
protection
of
expectations
so
relentlessly.
a)
Expectation Damages
in a
Credit Economy: Planning
and
Risk
Allocation
There
is a
lively
historical debate regarding
the
emergence
of
expecta-
tion damages
as the
standard measure
of
damages
in
contract.3
Many
believe that
the
development
was
related
to the
growing prominence
of
executory
contracts (agreements about
the
future)
in an
increasingly
market-oriented economy. There
are
several reasons
for
this. Expecta-
tion damages allow contracting parties
to
treat promises about
the
future
as
present values.
In a
complex market economy where actors
must plan
far in
advance
and
coordinate many
factors
in
order
to
pro-
duce goods
and
services, expectation damages provide
a
measure
of
certainty
in the
planning process. Mere reliance
or
restitution damages
2
L.L. Fuller
&
W.R. Purdue, "The
Reliance
Interest
in
Contract
Damages"
(1936)
46
Yale
L.J.
52.
3 M.
Horwitz,
The
Transformation
of
American
Law,
1780-1860
(Cambridge,
Mass.:
Harvard
University Press, 1977);
A.W.B.
Simpson, "The Horwitz Thesis
and the
History
of
Contracts" (1979)
46 U.
Chi.
L.
Rev. 533;
PS.
Atiyah,
The
Rise
and
Fall
of
Freedom
of
Contract
(New
York:
Oxford
University
Press,
1979).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT