Mitigation, Avoided Loss, and Time of Assessment

AuthorJamie Cassels/Elizabeth Adjin-Tettey
ProfessionProfessor of Law, Vice President Academic, and Provost, University of Victoria/Professor of Law, University of Victoria
Pages375-415
375
CHAPTER 12
MITIGATION,
AVOIDED LOSS, AND
TIME OF ASSESSMENT
A. MITIGATION OF DAMAGES
1) Introduction
Mitigation of damages is the principle that a plaintiff may not recover
losses that could have been avoided by taking reasonable steps after the
wrong. The principle applies in both tort and contract. The Supreme
Court of Canada has quoted with approval the following statement
from the House of Lords:
The fundament al basi s is thu s compensation for pecun iary lo ss nat-
urally f‌lowin g from the breach; but th is f‌irst principle is qualif‌ied by
a second, which imp oses on a pla intiff the duty of ta king all r eason-
able steps to m itigate the loss conseq uent on the bre ach, and debars
him from claiming any part of the damage which is due to his neglect
to take such steps.1
Another way of expressing the rule is that a plaintiff cannot recover
“avoidable losses.”2
1 British Westinghouse Electr ic & Manufacturing Co. Ltd. v. Underground Electri c
Rlys Co. of London Ltd., [1912] A.C. 673 at 689 (H.L.) [British Westinghouse],
quoted with approva l in Asamera Oil Corp. v. Sea Oil & General Corp. (1978),
[1979] 1 S.C.R. 633 at 661 [Asame ra].
2 Red Deer College v. Michaels, [1976] 2 S.C.R. 324 [Red Deer College].
REMEDIES: THE L AW OF DAMAGES376
There are sound reasons underlying the obligation to mitigate.
Most generally, mitigation is about fairne ss. Damages are not gener-
ally intended to be punitive. Following a tort or breach of contract, the
plaintiff may not hold t he defendant hostage to every loss that m ight
occur. Where the plaint iff is reasonably able to avoid a loss, or to t ake
steps to minimize it, it would be antisocial and punitive for the plaintiff
to sit back and do nothing, thus incurring an “unconscionable accumu-
lation”3 of damages. The rule of mitigation has the effect of minimizing
the total costs of the tort or breach of contract, thereby avoiding unduly
burdening or s urprising the defendant with an unexpected extent of
liability. It should be borne in mind that not all breaches of contract are
mala f‌ides or even intentional. There i s no general policy that contr act
breach should be punished. Similarly, most torts involve the unintend-
ed consequences of legitim ate activities. The rule of m itigation ref‌lects
a recognition that “accidents happen” and that no useful pur pose is
served by allowing the damages to increase in their after math.
The basic in sight that it is soc ially desirable to minimize the total
costs of a civil wrong ha s been formali zed by legal economists. The
rule of mitigation i s said to be eff‌icient in th at it provides an incentive
to mini mize the joint costs of an activity. More specif‌ically, in breach
of contr act cases, mitigation perm its “eff‌icient breach.” According to
this notion, where the cost to the promisor of performing a contract is
substantially more expensive than the loss to the other party from non-
performance, t he contract should not be performed. It is uneconomic,
and oppressive, to force completion of such contracts when any losses
to the innocent party can be compensated by damages. The theory also
applies when the promisor is able, by bre aching, to earn additional
prof‌its on an alternate transaction. Where the innocent party’s loss can
be fully compensated by an award of damages paid out of the additional
prof‌its, and there is sti ll a net gain to be earned on the alternate tran s-
action, it is eff‌icient (joint value is maximi zed) to permit the breaching
party to pur sue the altern ative transaction.4 The rule of mitigation, re-
quiring the innocent party to take steps to keep the costs of breach low,
further promotes this re sult.
The rule of mitigation also ensures a fair allocation of risks between
the part ies. Often the plaintiff i s in the be st (or only) position to deal
with the con sequences of a breach of contract or tort. In such circum-
3 Ibid.
4 R.A. Posner, Economic Analysis of L aw, 6th ed. (New York: Aspen, 2 003) at 120.
The Supreme Court of Can ada has approved the idea of eff‌icient br each: Bank of
America Cana da v. Mutual Trust Co., [2002] 2 S.C.R. 601 at para. 31.
Mitigation, Avoided Loss, a nd Time of Assessment 377
stances, it would be wrong to saddle defendants with post-breach risks
over which they have no control. For example, where a buyer of goods
breaches a contract of sale, the vendor h as an obligation to resell t he
goods. If the vendor does not do so and the goods spoil, or the market
price fa lls, that additional loss is caused as much by the vendor’s in-
action as by the buyer’s breach. Additionally, while the vendor in such
a case may choose to hold onto the goods rather than to resell them (in
the hope that the market price wil l increase), the risk of such specula-
tion should generally fall on the plaintiff’s shoulders rather than the
defendant’s (if the price doe s in fact increase, the plainti ff wil l be per-
mitted to retain the prof‌it).
2) General Principles: Reasonableness
The objective of the rule of mitigation is to give the plaintiff an incen-
tive to take steps to minimize the total costs of the tort or breach of
contract, and to avoid unduly burdening the defendant with avoidable
losses. The plaintiff i s debarred from recovering losses th at could rea-
sonably be avoided. Wh at is rea sonable i s a question of fact, not law,
and the burden of proof is upon the defendant to demonstrate that the
plaintiff could rea sonably have avoided a loss or was unreasonable in
her conduct.5 In assessing re asonableness, the context is important. In
the commercial context, plaintiffs must do what an ordinary business
person would do in the circumstances. They must take actions that are
consistent w ith t heir usu al practices and may not let t heir feelings of
hostility or anger get in the way. However, the plaintiff is not obliged to
make extraordina ry efforts or to take serious business risk s or gambles
to reduce a los s. The plainti ff need only do what is prudent under the
circumstances. Given that the plaint iff is often facing diff‌icult circum-
stances following an unexpected breach, t he actions t aken will not be
judged against too high a standard. Nor will cour ts perm it the actions
taken by the plaintiff to be easily second-guessed by the defendant with
the benef‌it of perfect hindsight. One court explained:
Where the sufferer from a breach of contract f‌inds himself i n con-
sequence of that breach placed in a position of embarrassment, the
measures wh ich he may be driven to adopt in order to extricate him-
5 Red Deer College, above note 2; Coutts v. Brian Jessel Aut osport Inc. (2005), 40
C.C.E.L. (3d) 236 (B.C.C.A.); Proctor Crushing Inc. v. Precision Surfacing Ltd.,
2004 ABQB 713 at pa ras. 72–73 [Proctor Crushing]; 2438667 Manitoba Ltd. v.
Husky Oil Ltd., [2007] M.J. No. 233 (C.A.); Kern v. Steele (2003), 220 N.S.R. (2d)
51 (C.A.).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT